Scholarship Repository
University of Minnesota Law School
Articles Faculty Scholarship
2023
Burdens of Proof in Establishing Negligence: A Comparative Law Burdens of Proof in Establishing Negligence: A Comparative Law
and Economics Analysis and Economics Analysis
Francesco Parisi
University of Minnesota Law School
Giampaolo Frezza
Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.umn.edu/faculty_articles
Part of the Law Commons
Recommended Citation Recommended Citation
Francesco Parisi & Giampaolo Frezza, Burdens of Proof in Establishing Negligence: A Comparative Law
and Economics Analysis, 9 Italian Law Journal 77-100 (2023)
This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the University of Minnesota Law School. It has been
accepted for inclusion in the Faculty Scholarship collection by an authorized administrator of the Scholarship
Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected], [email protected], [email protected].
Burdens of Proof in Establishing Negligence:
A Comparative Law and Economic Analysis
Francesco Parisi
*
and Giampaolo Frezza
**
Abstract
Inherent in any judicial system is the need to allocate the burden of proof on one party.
Within the realm of negligence torts, that burden is traditionally placed on the plaintiff,
meaning that the plaintiff must bring forth sufficient evidence to establish negligence by the
defendant. In effect, this is a legal presumption of non-negligence in favor of the defendant. In
some jurisdictions for specific torts, defendants are, instead, presumed negligent, therefore
requiring defendants to come forth with sufficient evidence to prove their due diligence. In
this paper, we discuss the legal origins and effects of these differences in a comparative law
and economics perspective. We explore the interesting interaction between evidence and
substantive tort rules in the creation of care and activity level incentives and discuss the
ideal scope of application of alternative legal presumptions under modern-age evidentiary
technology.
I. Introduction
Recent scientific and technological innovations have changed the landscape
of evidence practice quite substantially. New frontiers of evidence have been made
possible by genetic testing, computer recording of data, digital timestamping,
third-party certified data storage systems, black-box technology, traffic surveillance
cameras, satellite imaging, Snapshot
®
technology, and GPS tracking devices.
Though the usefulness and invasiveness into our private lives remain relevant
normative questions, these transformations have changed our routine information
protocols. Scientific and technological advances will continue to provide new
opportunities and open new horizons in the domain of legal evidentiary discovery.
Legal presumptions play two interrelated roles in negligence cases. First,
legal presumptions allocate the burden of proving negligence between the parties.
1
Oppenheimer & Donnelly Professor of Law, University of Minnesota, School of Law and
Professor of Economics, University of Bologna.
Provost and Professor of Private Law, University of Rome, LUMSA, Faculty of Law.
The authors would like to thank Michael Bennett, Ryan Fitzgerald, Nuno Garoupa, Alice
Guerra, Marco Li Pomi, Symeon Symeonides, and the participants to the 2021 Annual Conference of
the American Society of Comparative Law for valuable comments and suggestions.
1
The way in which allocation of the burden of proof affects both care decisions and incentives
to invest in information is well known outside the area of negligence liability, such as pointed out
in the context of US toxic torts by W.E. Wagner, ‘Choosing Ignorance in the Manufacture of
2023] Burdens of Proof in Establishing Negligence 78
Given the differing accessibilities to relevant evidence and information by the
parties, this may affect a courts ability to assess the defendant’s negligence in the
case at hand. Second, the use of different legal presumptions can affect the parties
expected liability and their incentives with respect to both care and activity levels.
In this paper, we employ a comparative law and economics perspective to
attempt to understand the interdependent relationship between new evidentiary
technology, legal presumptions, and discovery rules, with special focus on
negligence liability. The paper is structured as follows. In Section 2, we survey the
different legal presumptions of negligence used in European legal systems from
a historical and comparative perspective, with special attention to the rules
governing traffic accidents. Our analysis builds upon two separate bodies of
literature looking at the interaction between evidentiary and substantive rules in
tort law. We consider some of the theoretical and practical difficulties in the adoption
of presumptions of negligence. We examine the cheapest evidence-producer
criterion elaborated in the current literature and discuss the applications of this
criterion in the context of the US and European rules. In Section 3, we consider
the interrelated effects of legal presumptions on the parties tort incentives and
incentives to invest in private evidence technology. We discuss the possible
diluting effects of alternative discovery regimes on the partiesincentives to adopt
evidence technology. Section 4 concludes with policy considerations.
II. Presumptions of Negligence
The need to allocate the burden of proof on one party is inherent in any
judicial system. Traditionally, within the realm of negligence torts, that burden is
placed on the plaintiff. This means that the plaintiff must bring forth sufficient
evidence to establish negligence by the defendant. In effect, this is a legal
presumption in favor of defendants.
2
In some European jurisdictions, defendants
Toxic Products 82 Cornell Law Review, 773, 774–75 (1997). See also, eg, Restatement (Third)
of Torts: Products Liability §2 comment a (‘To hold a manufacturer liable for a risk that was not
foreseeable when the product was marketed might foster increased manufacturer investment in
safety. But such investment by definition would be a matter of guesswork’).
2
To frame the scope of our analysis, we should clarify some of the terminology that will be
used in our analysis, distinguishing interrelated concepts that are commonly associated with the
notion of ‘burden of proof.These concepts are operationally interdependent, but theoretically
distinct:legal presumptions,burden of production, andburden of persuasion. Legal presumptions
are rules that allocate the initial burden of production of evidence, specifying which party is
required to ‘produce’ the evidence (or, as J. Adler and M. J. Michael, The Nature of Judicial
Proof: An Inquiry into the Logical, Legal, and Empirical Aspects of the Law of Evidence (1931), 63
put it, which party has theburden of coming forward with the evidence). A favorable presumption
shifts the burden (and costs) of producing evidence on the other party. The concept of burden of
persuasion, instead, defines how evidence should be weighted and ‘how much probative evidence
should be offered to convince the fact finders. Standards of proofs, such as reasonable possibility,
preponderance of the evidence, clear and convincing evidence, or ‘beyond a reasonable doubt,
are standards that determine the applicable burden of persuasion. In this paper, we focus on the
79 The Italian Law Journal [Vol. 09 No. 01
are presumed negligent for specific torts, therefore requiring the defendant to
produce sufficient evidence of their non-negligence. These rules have gone through
periods of reformulation as the underlying principles of evidentiary production
and presumptions of negligence have changed.
1. Legal Socialism and the Origins of Presumed Negligence
Across European legal systems there are many diversified models of
presumptions of negligence.
3
In several countries, the fault principle of no
liability without negligence is strongly rooted, so most presumptions of negligence
have been introduced by special legislation. Because presumptions of negligence can
easily lead to presumed liability, or semi-strict liability, many countries have
found difficulty in accepting alternative presumption of negligence regimes. This
creates a tension with the underlying traditional general fault principle: in the
absence of proof of negligence, judges must leave things as they are.
4
Outside the area of traffic accidents, we can find trace the earlier examples
of rules of presumed negligence in modern codifications to the provisions
contained in the code Napoon of 1804.
5
In particular, Arts 1384, 1385, 1386 (in
the original version of the code) established liability for (i) custodians of property
that cause harm; (ii) parents for the harm caused by their cohabiting minor
children; (iii) employers for the harm caused by their employees; (iv) teachers
and craftsmen for the harm caused by their students and apprentices; (v) owners
of animals, or whoever is using the animal, for the harm the animals caused; and
(vi) owners of buildings for the harm caused by their collapse or destruction. In
their original formulation, however, these presumptions were a form of presumed
liability that did not admit rebuttal evidence and did not allow for avoidance of
liability (eg, fortuitous event or force majeure). These exceptions were only introduced
by French courts later in the 19
th
century, following the spread of civil wrongs
brought about by the industrial revolution.
6
Rules of presumed negligence have
effect that changes in the burden of producing evidence have on the parties care and activity level
incentives. Hereinafter, we’ll refer to the burden of production as ‘burden of proof. We compare the
traditional rules that place the initial burden of proof on the plaintiff (we refer to these rules as
presumptions of non-negligence), to the alternative rules introduced in Europe that have reallocated
the burden of proof on the defendant (we refer to these rules as ‘presumptions of negligence’). These
legal reforms have not modified the standards of proof applicable to the case, so we will set that
dimension of the probatory problem aside for the purpose of our analysis.
3
See G. Alpa, La responsabili civile, Trattato di diritto civile (Milano: Giuff, 1999), 313.
4
In these jurisdictions, only the legislature can introduce new cases governed by strict
liability. This is because strict liability is still considered one of the exceptions to the general fault
principle governing tort liability. Extensive interpretations or applications by analogy of the legal
presumptions of negligence would thus be inadmissible, since they would de facto introduce
new areas of semi-strict liability, infringing the general principle of fault liability.
5
See generally, M. Comporti, Fatti illeciti: le responsabili presunte, Il Codice Civile
Commentario (Milano: Giuffrè, 2012), 99.
6
See F. Laurent, Principes de droit civil (Paris: Librairie A. Marescq, Aine, 1878), 691; L.
Josserand, Cours de droit civil positif français (Paris: Recueil Sirey, 1932), 52353; R. Demogue,
2023] Burdens of Proof in Establishing Negligence 80
later appeared in several other European codifications.
Like the code Napoléon, the Spanish legal system included rules of presumed
liability in special circumstances which depart from the otherwise applicable
fault principle. Art 1903 of the Spanish Civil Code of 1889 encompasses these
forms of civil liability in a single provision, specifying that the obligations are
enforceable not only as a result of one’s own acts or omissions, but also of those
of such persons for whom one is liable. This includes parents being liable for the
harm caused by their children; guardians being liable for damages caused by minors
or incapacitated individuals under their supervision; owners or managers of a
company being liable for damages caused by their employees in the exercise of
employee functions; and teachers and schools being liable for damages caused by
students under their control during school and extracurricular activities. This rule
does not attach strict liability on the injurers or their supervisors,
7
as liability only
arises because the supervisors are presumed to have failed in their duties to
properly supervise, educate, or control those under their authority or control. In
other words, under Spanish law, defendants face a rebuttable presumption of
negligence. As specified by the last para of Art 1903 of the Spanish Civil Code,
8
to
avoid liability, a defendant must establish that he or she acted with the same
diligence as that of a reasonable person (a good family man), although the
undertaken precautions did not suffice to prevent the accident.
As discussed above, the drafters of Arts 1384, 1385, and 1386 of the code
Napoon initially took an intermediate position between a rule of strict liability
and a rule of presumed liability. The code also had a clear influence on the rules
introduced in Italy. Arts 11531156 of the Italian Civil Code of 1865 represent a
mere transplant of the French rules into the Italian system. Presumptions of
negligence are found in similar set of tort cases under Arts 2047, 2048, 2050, and
2054 of the Italian Civil Code of 1942. Unlike France, under both codifications,
Italian courts interpreted these presumptions as rebuttable from their initial
applications. Under Art 2047, para 1, of the Civil Code, in the event of damage
caused by an individual lacking legal capacity, the supervisor or guardian of the
individual becomes liable for the harm, unless they are able to prove that they
could not have prevented the harmful act.
9
According to Art 2048, the parents or
Traitè des obligations en génerale (Paris: Rousseau, 1925), 983; R. Savatier, Traitè de la responsabilité
civile en droit français (Paris: Librairie générale de droit et de jurisprudence, 1951), 421; H. Lalou,
Trai pratique de la responsabili civile (Paris: Dalloz, 1962), 665. On liability for risk, see n 7
below.
7
See Arts 1905, 1908 and 1910 of the Spanish Civil Code.
8
Art 1903 of the Spanish Civil Code: ‘The liability provided in the present Article shall cease
if the persons mentioned therein provide evidence that they acted with all the diligence of an
orderly [good family man] to prevent the damage.
9
Art 2047 Civil Code. According to Corte di Cassazione 26 January 2016 no 1321, in order
to be held not liable, it is necessary that the duty of care (of supervision), and its related liability,
be transferred to another subject by contract, by law, or some other mechanism. For the
presumption of liability provided by Art 2047 Civil Code, regarding who is liable for watching
81 The Italian Law Journal [Vol. 09 No. 01
guardians are liable for civil wrongs committed by non-emancipated minor children
or persons subject to their guardianship and who live with them.10 Moreover, para
2 states that teachers and those who teach a trade, art, or profession are liable for
any tort damages caused by their students or apprentices occurring while under
their supervision.
11
Under para 3, such teachers are exempted from liability if they
prove that they acted diligently or would have been unable to prevent the act.
12
In analyzing these topics, the literature frequently focuses on whether these
provisions operate as a rule of presumed negligence or, de facto, as one of strict
liability. The effects of a presumption of negligence can be seen in the concept of
imputed risk contained in these provisions and their wording. Liability can be
avoided on two interrelated grounds. First, the presumption can be overcome by
showing that due care was exercised in supervising the injurer and that the accident
occurred, notwithstanding the adoption of diligent precautions. Second, the
provisions explicitly allow for the parent or teacher who failed to take due care to
show that, even if they had taken reasonable precautions, they would not have
been able to prevent the accident. In this case liability can be avoided on causation
grounds, even in the shadow of the unrebutted presumption of negligence. In
other words, even if the supervisor had acted diligently, the accident could not have
been avoided.
13
A similar argument applies with respect to presumed culpa in
vigilando and presumed culpa in educando. According to Italian case law, to
rebut the presumption of negligence, the parent must prove that he has properly
educated and adequately supervised the child based on their age, character, and
nature (which in turn is a function of the environment, attitudes, and personality
of the child).
14
Short of that proof, the parent can still avoid liability on causation
grounds, demonstrating that a proper education and supervision would not have
been sufficient to prevent the accident.
over an unable person and for the admissibility of liability against the healthcare provider, see
Corte di Cassazione 20 June 2008 no 16803. According to Corte di Cassazione 12 December
2003 no 19060, the recovery of a firearm used as a toy by incapable children does not constitute
an exceptional and unforeseeable fact suitable to excuse a parent’s liability under Art 2047 Civil
Code, since the supervision of the incapable child must be constant and uninterrupted as well as
not occasional nor from a distance.
10
Art 2048 Civil Code.
11
ibid para 2. According to Corte di Cassazione 18 September 2015 no 18327, a parent’s
liability for the tort of the minor child exists pursuant to Art 2048 Civil Code and is not excused
even when the harmful behavior of the child was carried out in a place subject to the supervision of
others. For references regarding presumed liability, see generally Corte di Cassazione 22 April
2009 no 9542, Massimario Giustizia civile, 663 (2009); Corte di Cassazione, 20 October 2005
no 20322, Massimario Giustizia civile, 1919 (2005); Corte di Cassazione 28 March 2001 no
4481, Massimario Giustizia civile, 607 (2001).
12
Art 2048 Civil Code. See M. Franzoni, ‘Fatti illeciti’, in A. Scialoja and G. Branca eds,
Commentario al codice civile, Libro quarto: Obbligazioni, Art. 2043-2059 (Bologna-Roma:
Zanichelli, 1993), 326, 347, providing a detailed analysis of case law.
13
G. Alpa, Responsabilità civile e danno. Lineamenti e questioni (Bologna: il Mulino, 1991),
303.
14
See ibid 304-305, for references to cases.
2023] Burdens of Proof in Establishing Negligence 82
Legal presumptions of negligence are also present in Germany. The German
BGB of 1900 adopted the so-called binary system of legal presumptions:
this expression indicates all the various types of cases in which the
person is faced with liability not based on negligence deriving from an action or
omission, but rather grounded on a rebuttable presumption of negligence or,
at times, liability without negligence…’
15
This latter category includes cases of vicarious liability, where the principal is
liable for the harm caused by his agents in the performance of an activity. The
principal can avoid liability by proving that he used reasonable care in the choice
and supervision of the agent, or if the damage would have resulted even if
reasonable care had been exercised.
16
Similarly, supervisors of minors and legally
incapacitated individuals are liable for the harm caused by individuals subject to
their supervision, unless they can prove that they diligently fulfilled their duty of
care.
17
This second category also includes the liability of an animals owner and
keeper. An animal owner, under § 833 must compensate any individual who is
killed or injured by their animal, regardless of whether they exercised reasonable
care.
18
Under § 834, this provision is also applicable to those who supervise the
animal by contract for the owner.
19
Similarly, under §§ 836 837, whoever owns
or possesses property is liable for any harm caused by the collapse or destruction of
a building or any other structure on the land, unless the owner or possessor proves
that they exercised due care in preventing the risk of damage.
20
2. Presumed Negligence Rules for Enterprise and Motor Vehicle
Liability
At the end of the nineteenth century, in some European legal systems, we
observed a gradual transition from negligence-based models of liability to models of
liability based on the notion ofrisk creation. Legal academics belonging to the so-
calledlegal socialism’ movement in Italy and France
21
denounced the failure of
negligence as a general foundation of liability and developed what became
15
G. Alpa, n 4 above, 304.
16
BGB § 831.
17
ibid § 832. Note that in 1999, the Bürgerliches Gesetzbuch (BGB) was reformed. Liability for
obligations arising for minors was restricted. The new § 1629a provides that the financial liability
for transactions concluded before the eighteenth year by the legal representatives of the minor
(or personally by the minor with the consent of the legal representatives) is limited to assets that
exist upon reaching the age of majority. The limitation does not apply to liability coming from
wrongs committed by the minor. M. Löhnig and D. Schwab, La legge sulla limitazione di
responsabilità del minore’ Responsabilità civile e previdenza, 1215 (2000).
18
ibid § 833.
19
ibid § 834.
20
ibid §§ 836-837.
21
See P. Ungari, ‘In memoria del socialismo giuridico Politica del diritto, 248 (1970); A.
Loria, Socialismo giuridico La scienza del diritto privato, 519 (1893).
83 The Italian Law Journal [Vol. 09 No. 01
known as the risk theory of profit.
22
The idea centered on the premise that the
risk generated by a firm through its economic activity is a risk that needed to be
considered as a cost of production. Theories of liability that were developed based
on the risk theory of profit reframed negligence liability by creating a presumption
of liability on the person who generated the risk, unless proven otherwise.
23
This
intellectual evolution led to the paradigms of strict liability or semi-strict liability
and the broader use of legal presumptions of negligence.
From a functional perspective, rules of presumed negligence should not be
confused with the Common law doctrine of res ipsa loquitur. Under the rule of
res ipsa loquitur, courts depart from the traditional presumption of non-negligence
because the facts are so obvious that requiring parties to argue any further would
be redundant and contrary to procedural economy.
24
This principle of law, also
known in Germany as prima facie-Beweiss, is particularly widespread in other
civil law systems: the fact that a harm has occurred provides prima facie evidence
of the wrongdoers negligence.
25
In several European jurisdictions, drivers of vehicles not guided by rails (ie,
vehicles other than trains), are presumed negligent and thus face semi-strict
22
For a presentation of the legal socialism movement and the risk theory of profit developed by
A. Loria, see G. Frezza and F. Parisi, Achille Loria (1847-1943) (Elgar Companion to Law and
Economics, J.G. Backhaus ed, 1999), 392402.
23
M. Philonenko,Faute et risque cé par les énergies accumulées’ Revue trimestrielle de
droit civil, 305 (1950).
24
See A. Guerra, B. Luppi and F. Parisi, ‘Do Presumptions of Negligence Incentivize
Optimal Precautions? 53 European Journal of Law and Economics, 511-533 (2022). According
to the exemplary quote of Chief Justice Erle,there must be reasonable evidence of negligence.
But where the thing is shown to be under the management and control of the defendant or his
servants, and the accident is such as in the ordinary course of things does not happen if those
who have management use proper care, it affords reasonable evidence, in the absence of
explanation by the defendants, that the accident arose from want of care.Scott v. London & St.
Katherine Docks Co. (1865) 159 Eng. Rep. 685; see also Byrne v. Boadle (1863) 159 Eng. Rep.
299, 300–01. In the US, a minority of states find that res ipsa loquitur creates a presumption of
negligence, including California and Colorado. See, eg, Blackwell v. Hurst, 54 Cal. Rptr. 2d 209
(Cal. Ct. App. 1996); Stone’s Farm Supply, Inc. v. Deacon, 805 P.2d 1109 (Col. 1991).
25
See P.G. Monateri, La responsabilità civile. Le fonti delle obbligazioni (Torino: UTET,
1998), 11; V. Fineschi, Res ipsa loquitur: un principio in divenire nella definizione della responsabilità
medica Rivista italiana medicina legale, 419 (1989). Along these lines, the Italian Supreme Court
affirmed that ‘in matters of tort liability, it is up to the plaintiff, who sues for damages, to put
forth evidence of the injurers negligence; this principle, however, does not necessarily imply that
the judge requires negligence be proven exclusively from the evidence offered by the injured party,
as the proof can be inferred from the facts and circumstances of the specific case. The evidence
can also be presumptive, and, in this regard, a fact can be inferred circumstantially due to the id
quod plerumque accidit rule, taking into consideration that it is not always easy to acquire direct
evidence.That specific case dealt with products liability, and more specifically, involved a bottling
company sued for damage caused by the bursting of a bottle containing a carbonated beverage.
Corte di Cassazione 28 October 1980 no 5795; G. Monateri, above, 111. There is no general rule
that indicates when it is possible to apply res ipsa loquitur or other presumptive inferences based
on the id quod plerumque accidit because they are called upon to operate based on circumstantial
evidence and findings of the specific case. ibid 114.
2023] Burdens of Proof in Establishing Negligence 84
liability for any harm caused to people or things while operating the vehicle,
unless the driver or operator is able to prove that he has undertaken reasonable
precautions to avoid the harm.
In the field of traffic accidents, Germany adopted a mix of strict liability and
presumed negligence rules, as early as 1909. Specifically, the Liability Provisions of
§ 7 of the German Road Traffic Act (Strassenverkehrsgesetz, hereinafter StVG)
provides the central rule establishing a form of semi-strict liability for the owner
or keeper (eg, lessor) of a motor vehicle, for the damage caused by the operation
of the vehicle killing, injuring, or creating material damage to third parties. In
such cases, liability can only be avoided showing that the accident was the result
of force majeure, or the vehicle was used without the knowledge and permission of
the owner.
26
When the driver is not the owner, the Traffic Act introduces a second
ground for avoiding liability under § 18 StVG, allowing the operator to prove that the
loss was not due to his or her fault.
27
Under this rule, liability can be avoided also
by the owner and the keeper by showing that due care was exercised or that the
accident was not caused by the failed adoption of diligent precautions.
28
Under
the German Traffic Act § 17, when an accident occurs between two motor vehicles, a
rule of presumed liability applies. In such cases, liability is apportioned according to
the circumstances and the principles of comparative negligence and can only be
entirely avoided by the parties by proving they have acted with due care.
29
3. Presumed Joint Negligence Rules
The Italian rules presuming negligence in traffic accidents are a bit more
elaborate, leaving less room for discretionary evaluations based on the circumstances
of the case if parties cannot prove to have acted with due care. Art 1156 of the
Italian Civil Code of 1865 introduced, for the first time, joint liability for torts
ascribable to more than one person. Based on this rule, the current civil code
uniquely applies joint liability for vehicles coupled with a presumption of negligence.
Italys regime resulted in a novel legal rule, creating a legalpresumption of joint
negligence for accidents between motor vehicles.
30
This interesting spin on legal
26
See § 7 StVG: If a person is killed or injured or material damage incurred from the
operation of a motor vehicle, the owner of the vehicle is obligated to compensate the injured
party for the resulting loss, unless the accident was the result of force majeure, or the vehicle was
used without the knowledge and permission of the owner’.
27
§ 18 StVG: ‘In the cases of § 7(1), the operator is also liable to pay compensation pursuant
to §§ 815, unless the loss is not the fault of the operator.This amounts to a reversal of the
burden of proof (Beweislastumkehr) on the issue of negligence.
28
Van Dam (2013, 412) point out that German case law has found drivers not negligent
when they prove to have taken the level of due care of ‘the ideal driver who takes into account
the considerable chance that other people make mistakes.BGH 17 March 1992, BGHZ 117, 337;
BGH 28 May 1985, NJW 1986, 183.
29
Although not explicitly stating so, § 17 StVG de facto introduces a rebuttable presumption of
joint negligence, like the Italian rule of presumed joint liability discussed in the text.
30
G. Frezza and F. Parisi, Responsabilità civile e analisi economica (Milano: Giuffrè, 2006), 93.
85 The Italian Law Journal [Vol. 09 No. 01
presumptions specifies that in the event of a collision, unless proven otherwise,
parties are presumed jointly negligent. According to this rule, it is presumed that
each party equally contributed to producing the harm and is proportionally liable
to compensate for the harm suffered by each vehicle (ie each driver is presumed
equally negligent and liable for fifty percent of the damages caused).
31
As originally
written, this rule only applied when the collision resulted in harm to both vehicles.
The Italian Constitutional Court found this to be unconstitutional.
32
The
Constitutional Court stated that the presumption of bilateral negligence and the
resulting joint liability should also apply when only one of the vehicles has
suffered harm in the accident, indicating that the presumption of joint liability
was based on evidentiary principles, and was not created for the purpose of
spreading the accident loss between the parties.
33
The evidence needed to rebut the presumption of joint liability consists of
proving that the drivers undertook reasonable precautions to avoid the accident. To
avoid their share of liability, drivers must show that they obeyed all relevant
traffic rules and undertook reasonable precautions, under the circumstances of
the case.
34
Furthermore, Italian law includes a specific rule for the collision between
vehicles, both those moving and those temporarily parked.
35
In these cases,
concurrent liability of drivers is presumed until proven otherwise. In tort situations
involving two or more parties, each party is assumed to have contributed equally to
the accident, even when the vehicle was not moving. Each party bears the burden
of producing evidence. Paradoxically, the owner of the parked car may be in a
worse position to produce evidence, notwithstanding the fact that in most cases
a parked car is less involved in the causation of an accident.
If only one party can produce satisfactory evidence about their diligent behavior,
the other party is held unilaterally negligent and bears the entire loss, as injurer
(facing full liability) or as victim (facing the full loss, with no compensation).
When neither party can prove his or her diligent behavior, the Italian rule leads
to a sharing of the loss, like a rule of comparative negligence. Liability increases
31
Art 2054 civil code. For an articulated analysis of applicable case law, see generally M.
Franzoni, n 12 above, 326-347. According to Corte di Cassazione 23 October 2014 no 22514, the
principle stated by Art 1227 civil code (also applicable to tort law due to the express reference
contained in Art 2056 of civil code) of the proportional reduction of damage based on the
percentage entity of the causal efficiency of the injured party applies not only to the injured party,
which claims compensation for the harm directly suffered, but also against the relatives who, in
relation to the reflected effects on them, start legal action in order to be redressed for the damage
suffered iure proprio.
32
Corte costituzionale 14 December 1972 no 205.
33
ibid
34
Corte di Cassazione 19 September 1980 no 5321; Corte di Cassazione 21 June 1979 no
3443. Additional discussion can be found in G. Spina, ‘L’accertamento della responsabilità da
sinistro stradale nella recente giurisprudenza. Profili sostanziali e giurisprudenziali Responsabilità
civile e previdenza, 1806 (2014).
35
G. Alpa, n 3 above, 711.
2023] Burdens of Proof in Establishing Negligence 86
and decreases in relation to the extent of the proven negligence of the driver.
36
When both parties can prove their diligent behavior, each party bears the loss
suffered in the accident and no liability or compensation is owed to one another.
Other European legal systems, including the Netherlands introduced rules of
presumed liability, creating rebuttable presumptions of negligence against injurers.
In the Netherlands, however, a stronger presumption applies in favor of victims
of motor vehicle accidents. Art 185 (1), Wegenverkeerswet (Road Law), 1994:
If a vehicle driven on the road is involved in a road accident, causing
damage to persons or things (not to another motor vehicle), the owner or
keeper of the vehicle is liable to compensate the harm, unless he can be
proved that the accident was due to force majeure or by a person, for whom
the owner or the keeper are not responsible.
According to these European rules of presumed liability, evidence of harm and
causation are sufficient elements to establish liability, effectively shifting the
burden onto the defendant to show that he behaved diligently. Thus, in the event
of an accident, injurers are by default liable and must pay full compensation unless
they can rebut the presumption by proving their own diligence or showing that the
victims behavior was itself negligent or not foreseeable, or that the accident was
somehow not avoidable.
Other countries are debating a change from the conventional presumption
36
According to Tribunale di Catania 7 May 2020 no 1497, ‘the concrete ascertainment of
the fault of one of the drivers does not involve the overcoming of the joint liability presumption
of the other if the latter has not concretely provided satisfactory evidence relating to the lack of
any possible charge against him’. Tribunale di Grosseto 7 May 2020 no 324 believes that in car
accidents, para 2 of Art 2054 of the Italian Civil Code provides a presumption of liability for both
drivers of vehicles involved in an accident. In this regard, the aforementioned rule does not constitute
a strict liability hypothesis for the driver, but rather one of presumed liability. The driver can
overcome this presumption by proving that he has done everything possible to avoid the damage,
or by demonstrating sufficient diligence, ie, behavior free of negligence and in compliance with the
traffic laws, as evaluated by the judge accounting for the circumstances of the specific case. In this
sense, the presumption of negligence has a merely subsidiary function and operates only when it
is impossible to determine the concrete extent of the respective liabilities. In other words, if the
negligence of one driver is ascertainable, the other driver is exempt from the presumption of
liability and is not required to prove that he has done everything possible to avoid the damage.
According to the Tribunale di Pisa 25 March 2020 no 354, the first para of Art 2054 of the Italian
Civil Code contemplates a form of presumed liability that can be overcome by the driver proving
that he has done everything possible to avoid the damage. For example, if a driver strikes a pedestrian
outside of a crosswalk, then the driver may avoid joint liability by demonstrating that the
pedestrian failed to give the driver the right of way, resulting in an unforeseeable and inevitable
obstacle, and that the driver had otherwise behaved correctly. According to Corte di Cassazione
20 marzo 2020 no 7479, on the subject of a collision between vehicles, the presumption of joint
liability established by Art 2054, para 2, of the Civil Code has a subsidiary function, operating only
in the event that the evidentiary findings do not allow to ascertain in a concrete manner to what
extent the conduct of the two drivers caused the damage and to allocate the actual liability for the
accident (in the specific case, two different technical experts were not allowed to reconstruct the
exact dynamics of the accident).
87 The Italian Law Journal [Vol. 09 No. 01
of non-negligence to presumed liability in various tort situations.
37
The push to
shift the burden of proof from victims to injurers is advanced on several grounds.
One argument is that a shift in the burden of proof would provide protection to
more vulnerable road users, such as cyclists (in accidents with motorcycles, cars,
trucks, etc) and pedestrians (in accidents with cyclists, motorcycles, cars, trucks,
etc), as well as victims below the age of sixteen and over seventy and disabled
individuals. Advocates say these rules are needed for both fairness and efficiency
reasons. Another argument is that the shift in the burden of proof onto the injurer is
fairer than the standard fault-based evidence rule, as it shields more vulnerable
victims from the burdensome task of proving the negligence of their injurer.
38
Yet
other arguments in support of the presumption of negligence point to the
widespread availability and rapid development of new evidence technologies,
such as helmet cameras, black-box technology, and GPS location technologies,
which make it easier for injurers to record accident events and provide evidence
to rebut a presumption of negligence.
As will be discussed below, a jurisdictions choice of which party should bear the
burden of proof can have a significant impact on the parties’ tort incentives, as
well as on their incentives to invest in private evidence. Given the new range of
evidentiary technologies, the choice of legal presumptions would benefit from a
broader reassessment. In Section 3, we will offer a broad-brush outline of some
of the relevant considerations, which we frame under the general umbrella of the
cheapest-evidence-producer criterion.
III. The Effect of Legal Presumptions on Tort Incentives
As pointed out by Castronovo, presumptions of liability in contemporary
legal systems are
a dogmatically heterogeneous category because they combine the
presumption, that is a qualification of the fact, with the resulting liability,
that is a judicial effect.
39
While the policy rationales and theoretical foundations of the presumptions of
negligence vary greatly across jurisdictionsfrom simple inversions of the burden
of proof for procedural economy or fairness, to goals of risk-spreading between
the parties, to other policy objectivesthe legal and economic consequences of
37
In the UK see the Parliamentary debate 24 March 2011, Parl Deb HC (2011) col. 1222 W
81 (UK).
38
R.H. Grzebieta, J. Olivier and S. Boufous, ‘Reducing the Rate of Serious Injuries to
Cyclists Medical Journal of Australia, 242 (2017); S. Boufous,It Is Time to Consider a Presumed
Liability Law that Protects Cyclists and Other Vulnerable Road Users 28 Journal of the Australasian
College of Road Safety, 65 (2017).
39
C. Castronovo, Sentieri di responsabilità civile europeaEuropa e diritto privato, 797 (2008).
2023] Burdens of Proof in Establishing Negligence 88
these presumptions are straightforwardly uniform: when there is a lack of evidence
pertaining to the relevant facts that led to an accident, a shift in legal presumptions
turns a case that would have favored the defendant into a case favoring the plaintiff
(or a splitting of the loss, under the Italian rule of presumed joint negligence for
motor vehicle accidents).
40
1. Effects of Presumptions of Negligence Under Alternative Liability
Regimes
Shifts in burdens of production of evidence are not neutral to truth-finding.
Shifting the burden from one party to the other unavoidably affects the parties
respective probabilities of success in litigation. To the extent to which the case
has one objective truth, the fact that the burden of proof affects the parties
likelihood of success in litigation must also imply that shifts in the burden will
affect the probability that one or another type of judicial errors (Type-I or Type-
II) takes place. Think of automobile accidents. A presumption in favor of defendant
reduces the probability of imposing liability on a negligent driver, while a
presumption in favor of plaintiffs increases the probability of imposing liability
on a non-negligent driver.
The effects of these errors are not only distributive.
41
Besides the obvious
desire to reduce the frequency of judicial errors, it is also important to consider
the effect that different types of errors may have on tort incentives.42 The associated
social cost may differ, given the effects of these errors on the incentives of prospective
injurers and prospective victims. When parties expect probatory difficulties, legal
presumptions shift care incentives from one party to another.
When shielded by a presumption of non-negligence in their favor, injurers
may strategically rely on their victims difficulty in satisfying their burden of proof.
This may dilute their precautionary care incentives. As probatory difficulties increase,
a negligence ruler with a non-negligence presumption gradually degenerates into
a no liability rule, entirely diluting potential injurers care incentives. The adoption
40
See G.A. Micheli et al, L’onere della prova (Padova: CEDAM, 1942), 313.
41
There is nothing deterministic about the optimal allocation of the burden of proof in the
face of the possible judicial errors. By shifting the burden from one party to the other, the
probability of error also shifts from one party to the other party. For example, a presumption in
favor of the defendant (like the traditional negligence rule) may give him an advantage and lead
to a margin of error in his favor (a fraction of cases may be erroneously decided in favor of the
defendant when the plaintiff is unable to prove the negligence of his injurer). The adoption of a
presumption in favor of the plaintiff, however, creates a mirror-image problem, giving the
plaintiff an evidentiary advantage that may lead to a margin of error in his favor (a smaller or
larger fraction of cases may be erroneously decided in favor of the plaintiff when the defendant
is unable to prove his diligence).
42
As pointed out by R. Cooter, D. Robert and A. Porat, Does Risk to Oneself Increase the Care
Owed to Others? Law and Economics in Conflict 29 Journal Legal Studies, 19-34 (2000), prospective
victims will not necessarily act differently depending on the legal liability rule-prospective victims
who are already facing substantial risks of serious personal injury that vary with the degree of care
that they take, are not affected by changes in liability rules, except in very rare cases.
89 The Italian Law Journal [Vol. 09 No. 01
of legal presumptions of negligence could correct this problem. When faced with
a presumption of negligence, probatory difficulties shift the expected accident loss
on injurers. As probatory difficulties increase, a negligence rule with a presumption
of negligence gradually degenerates into a rule of strict liability, inducing injurers to
undertake efficient care. The choice of presumptions of negligence can thus be
desirable to mitigate the diluting effects of judicial errors on injurers tort incentives.
However, the same reasoning applies with respect to the legal presumptions
applicable to victims. When shielded by a presumption of non-negligence in their
favor, prospective victims may strategically rely on their injurers difficulty in proving
their contributory or comparative negligence, and this may dilute the victims care
incentives. As probatory difficulties increase, the incentives created by a defense
of contributory or comparative negligence may gradually disappear entirely. The
adoption of legal presumptions of joint negligence, like those adopted in some
European jurisdictions for traffic accidents, corrects this problem. When faced with
a presumption of joint negligence, probatory difficulties shift the burden of proof
back on victims. As probatory difficulties increase, prospective victims will fear being
barred from receiving full compensation, inducing them to undertake efficient
care.
43
The adoption of presumptions of joint negligence can thus be desirable to
mitigate the effect that judicial errors may have on both victimsand injurerstort
incentives.
A second effect of legal presumptions and discovery regimes is on the parties
activity levels. As discussed above, in a world of imperfect adjudication, a shift of
the burden of proof also transfers the cost of legal errors. A change in legal
presumptions would affect the cost and desirability of a given activity, due to the
shift in expected liability associated with the ability to satisfy the burden of proof.
More specifically, a presumption that shifts the burden towards the defendant
increases the expected cost of the defendants activity. This is because, in the event
of an accident, the defendant will have to incur the cost of producing evidence, or
bear the liability associated with his inability to produce evidence (even when his
behavior was non-negligent).
The costs associated with the burden of proof can be analogized to a tax
imposed on the risk-generating activity. This tax will reduce the optimal level of
activity for the party facing the burden of proof. Those familiar with the economic
analysis of tort law will soon realize that this effect could be a curse or a blessing,
depending on which party bears the burden.
44
This is because the burden of
43
For a formal analysis of the effects of legal presumptions on care incentives in the presence of
judicial errors, see A. Guerra, B. Luppi and F. Parisi, n 24 above.
44
As per Shavell’s activity level theorem, no negligence-based regime can incentivize
optimal activity levels for both parties. This is because the party who does not bear the residual
liability is only concerned about avoiding liability by undertaking due care and does not internalize
the additional cost of non-negligent accidents. Conversely, the bearer of residual liability wants
to avoid harm altogether and will be incentivized to undertake both optimal care and optimal
activity level. The cost imposed by the burden of proof can therefore do either of two things: sub-
2023] Burdens of Proof in Establishing Negligence 90
proof imposes a tax on activity level which can alternatively distort the already
optimal incentives of the residual bearer or mitigate the inefficiently high activity
levels of the party who does not bear the residual loss. The optimal use of the
burden of proof as an activity level tax requires the creation of a legal presumption
in favor of the party burdened with the accident loss when both parties acted
diligently. This would entail imposing the burden on the defendant when the dispute
arises under negligence-based regimes (ie, simple negligence, negligence with
contributory negligence, or negligence with comparative negligence) and instead
shifting the burden on the plaintiff when the dispute arises under strict liability
regimes (ie, strict liability with contributory negligence, or strict liability with
comparative negligence). Accordingly, the European rules of presumed joint
negligence create a desirable alignment of incentives, bringing the activity levels
of both parties closer to the socially optimal levels.
2. The Negative-Proof Problem and the Role of Evidence Technology
One of the common explanations for the use of presumptions of non-
negligence and the allocation of evidentiary burdens on plaintiffs (in establishing the
fault of their injurers) is that if plaintiffs did not have the burden, there could be
an increase in potentially litigation, including a substantial fraction with little
merit, brought to extract settlements from defendants. In the absence of fee-shifting
rules or other correctives against frivolous claims, defendants might settle a case
for a positive amount to avoid having to spend a greater amount proving that they
were not negligent. The availability of new evidence technologies has reduced the
cost of evidence production and the reliability of the evidence produced by
defendants who invested in due care, weakening the practical rationales for the
adoption of presumptions of non-negligence in tort cases.
Further, the availability of new evidence technologies has mitigated a theoretical
and practical objection that was frequently raised against the use of legal
presumptions of negligence. The objection consisted in the fact that a burden placed
on the defendant would often entail a negative proof and would de facto deteriorate
into a semi-strict or strict liability rule. The procedural laws of evidence were
traditionally viewed as embracing this basic principle by allocating the burden of
proof on plaintiffs; shifting the burden of proof on the person denying an assertion
or a claim would constitute a logical fallacy, creating a presumption of truthfulness
of the claim unless otherwise disproven. According to this principle, the victim
optimally reduce the activity levels of the residual bearer or mitigate the excessive activity level
incentives of the non-residual bearer. Shavell’s proposition has become known in the law and
economics literature as Shavell’s activity level theorem.See F. Parisi, The Language of Law and
Economics: A dictionary (Cambridge: University Press, 2013) for the standard restatement of this
theorem. An ideal remedy in tort law should instead incentivize optimal precautionary care levels and
optimal activity levels for both parties. S. Shavell, ‘Strict Liability Versus Negligence 9 The Journal of
Legal Studies, 1 (1980), showed that this ideal is not achievable under negligence-based regimes,
because only the bearer of residual liability will have incentives to mitigate its activity level.
91 The Italian Law Journal [Vol. 09 No. 01
should bear the burden of proof of the elements of negligence necessary to establish
the injurers liability, because shifting the burden of proving the non-existence of
those elements on the injurer would reproduce the same logical fallacy. By
creating a presumption of negligence, the injurer would face the formidable burden
of proving a negativethe lack of negligence on his part. This would create a
presumption of truthfulness of the tort claim, unless successfully disproven by
the defendant.
The implicit premise of this argument is that negations often involve universal
negatives, while affirmations do not. The proof of a universal negative is what
ancient Romans called probatio diabolica (literally,devil’s proof’), to signify its
heinous difficulty. Consider, as an example, the allegation of a fact: ‘Defendant
signed a contract promising X. A signed document and a few additional pieces
of corroborating evidence would suffice to establish such an assertion. On the
contrary, the negative claim by defendantI have never signed a contract promising
X would entail the proof of a universal negative, necessitating omniscience and
omnipresence on the part of the defendant, and ultimately requiring the
examination of a potentially infinite amount of evidence by the factfinder.
Despite its logical soundness, in todays world, the negative-proof argument
presents a more limited logical objection to the use of legal presumptions of
negligence. Consider the case of a negligence tort. Contrary to the example used
to illustrate the negative-proof fallacy, proving the non-negligence of the injurer
at the time of the accident (or, for this matter, proving that any other element of
the tort is not present) does not entail the proof of a universal negative requiring
omniscience and omnipresence-proving non-negligence amounts to proving due
diligence.
The logical foundations of the law of proof do not dictate that in this case the
burden of proof should necessarily be placed on the plaintiff making an assertion
or a claim.
45
While at times it may be easier for a plaintiff to prove the negligence
of the defendant, in other situations it may be easier for a defendant to prove his
own diligence. Neither type of proof requires supernatural abilities. The choice of
an optimal allocation of the burden of proof in these cases hinges upon a test of
comparative advantage in the access to relevant information. Ceteris paribus, when
the factual premises of the negative-proof argument do not hold, the party who
has a comparative advantage in providing truthful evidence (hereinafter, the
cheapest evidence producer) should bear the burden of proof.
45
The inapplicability of the philosophical constructs to the legal notions of burden of proof and
choice of legal presumptions was pointed out in the early 1930s by Columbia law professor
Jerome Michael and Chicago philosopher and law professor Mortimer Adler, who observed:
The principles of logic do not place upon either party any burden of proving the propositions
which they have respectively alleged. The principles of logic are concerned only with the validity
and the structure of the processes by which proof and disproof are accomplished. M. Adler and J.
Michael, The Nature of Judicial Proof: An Inquiry into the Logical, Legal, and Empirical Aspects of
the Law of Evidence (New York: Colombia Law Review, 1931), 60.
2023] Burdens of Proof in Establishing Negligence 92
The test of comparative advantage is informed by some general assumptions
and guiding rules of thumb. For example, when the standard of due care entails
the undertakings of many actions, proof of diligence can be more burdensome than
the proof of negligence. Proof of negligence could be satisfactorily obtained by
showing that any one of the required actions had not been undertaken. Proof of
diligence would instead require evidence that each and every required precautionary
action was undertaken. In the limiting case in which an infinite number of actions
need to be undertaken to satisfy due care, a negative proof of non-negligence
would become virtually impossible. Thankfully, no such infinite list of burdensome
duties of care is legally expected from ordinary humans.
46
If, as it seems, there is nothing fundamentally necessary behind the idea of
placing the burden of proof on plaintiffs, the next logical question becomes
identifying the factors that should drive the optimal allocation of the burden of
proof. On this matter, it is important to consider that new technology is substantially
increasing the amount of information that can be acquired and preserved, with
far-reaching applications in the field of legal evidence and discovery. Scientific
and technological innovations play a dual role in evidence and discovery. Some
technologies can give factfinders insights, allowing them to look back and gather
information about past events, while others record and preserve present information
for future uses. We shall refer to the first group asinvestigative technologies and
to the second group as fact-keeping technologies.
1. Investigative Technologies. The characteristic feature of investigative
technologies is that they can be employed ex post even though no such technology
was used or available at the time of the event. Consider, for example, evidence
obtained through genetic testing. Like a lie detector, genetic testing can shed light
on past events. This technology need not be adopted by the parties at the time of
the original event but instead can be deployed when a need for discovery arises
later.
2. Fact-Keeping Technologies. Other technologies collect information about
present events and preserve it for future investigations. This category encompasses
two subgroups. The first is technology that can be adopted by parties who are
neither prospective injurers nor victims, including local governmental authorities,
such as traffic surveillance cameras and satellite imaging, capable of documenting
facts and events that occur within their range. We shall refer to them aspublic
fact-keeping technologies. The second involves technologies that individuals and
firms can privately adopt. These are instruments that are tailored to a specific set
of applications, determined by their user. Examples that fall within this category
include adoption of black-box technology on vessels, cameras on body vests or
helmets, Snapshot
®
and dash-mounted cameras on cars, use of digital timestamp
46
For a collection of cases describing the innumerable list of duties that a ‘reasonable man
should fulfill to avoid being held negligent in torts, see the humorous book by A.P. Hebert,
Uncommon Law (London: Methuen, 1937), 3–11.
93 The Italian Law Journal [Vol. 09 No. 01
certification methods, use of electronic tamper-proof data storage systems
managed and certified by third parties, and various applications of GPS technology.
We shall refer to them asprivate fact-keeping technologies. Private fact-keeping
technologies consist of two distinct subgroups, each with different focuses and
applications. Some technologies, such as black-box technology, Google Timeline®,
Snapshot®, and cloud data storage, are better able to track the users own actions.
We shall refer to them as first-party evidence technologies.Other technologies,
such as private surveillance cameras, fingerprints and face recognition devices,
are better able to document the activity of others. We shall refer to them as third-
party evidence technologies.
As will be discussed below, these evidence technologies have changed the
relative cost and reliability of providing evidence in a court proceeding, and thus
altered the resulting optimal allocation of burdens of production under the cheapest-
evidence-producer criterion.
3. Accuracy of Tort Adjudication and the Effects of Adversarial
Discovery
As Alice Guerra and Francesco Parisi pointed out, much of the conventional
wisdom underlying the choice of legal presumptions rests on the now-outdated
assumption that the amount of evidence available in any given situation (eg, the
number of witnesses or the amount of physical evidence available after an
accident) is not controlled by the parties. The advent of new evidence technology has
radically changed this situation. Individuals involved in a prospective accident
can endogenously control the amount of available evidence with the adoption of
evidence technology.
47
In this respect, legal presumptions influence the type of evidence technology
likely to be adopted. As summarized in Table 1 below, under traditional presumptions
of non-negligence, prospective injurers have limited incentives to invest in first-
party evidence technology, since in the event of an accident, it would primarily be
the victims burden to come forth with the necessary evidence. Prospective victims
would instead have incentives to adopt third-party evidence technology to prove
the negligence of their injurers. The opposite would hold under legal presumptions
of negligence. In this case, prospective injurers would be more likely to adopt first-
party evidence technology, and victims would have fewer incentives to invest in
third-party evidence technology. Presumptions of joint negligence would, instead,
incentivize both parties to invest in first-party evidence technology. Under this latter
presumption, prospective injurers would prevalently adopt evidence technology
focused on themselves to prove their non-negligence, and prospective victims
would similarly adopt evidence technology focused on themselves to prove lack of
47
A. Guerra and F. Parisi, ‘Investing in Private Evidence: The Effect of Adversarial Discovery
14 Journal of Legal Analysis, 657–671 (2021).
2023] Burdens of Proof in Establishing Negligence 94
contributory or comparative negligence. Hence, both parties would have greater
incentives to adopt first-party evidence technology.
Table 1: Legal Presumptions and Adoption of Evidence Technology
Injurers Evidence
Technology
Victims Evidence
Technology
Presumption of Non-
Negligence
Third-Party Focused
Presumption of
Negligence
First-Party Focused
Presumption of Joint
Negligence
First-Party Focused
First-Party Focused
The availability of new evidence technology increases the verifiability of
diligent and/or negligent behavior, increasing the benefits of the owners investment
in precautions. Precautions decrease the probability of an accident, but also help
individuals prove their diligent behavior to avoid liability. By increasing the ex
post verifiability of the parties behavior, evidence technology reinforces the parties
incentives to act diligently. An increase in evidence and accuracy of adjudication
will change the relative price of negligent versus non-negligent behavior. A burden
placed on the defendant increases the wedge between the payoffs in cases of
diligent versus non-diligent behavior. That is to say, the relative payoff of diligent
behavior over non-diligent behavior is increased, causing a substitution effect.
48
These investments may lead to desirable adjustments in the parties care investments.
Think, for example, of a motorcyclist fearing to harm pedestrians in a regime of
presumed negligence. In the event of an accident, the motorcyclist would have to
prove lack of negligence to avoid liability. Evidence technology could help him
satisfy the required burden of proof. The motorcyclist may thus put a dashcam on
his motorcycle to present footage of the accident in a courtroom. Evidence technology
renders past behavior more verifiable and increases the value of his investments
in precautions. This would strengthen the motorcyclists incentives to act diligently
48
As shown in the law and economics literature, for a sufficiently moderate cost of evidence,
this substitution effect should not be observed given the discontinuity of payoffs created by a
negligence standard.
95 The Italian Law Journal [Vol. 09 No. 01
and to undertake the due level of care, further reducing the probability that he
will find himself in the role of injurer in the event of an accident. The overall care
level incentives created by legal presumptions of negligence would be further
amplified by the adoption of presumptions of joint negligence. Under presumptions
of joint negligence, both parties would adopt technology that increase the value of
their care investments, making them more verifiable.
49
It should be further observed that evidence rules concerning discoverability
of evidence can play an important role in determining the parties’ decisions to
invest in evidence technology.
50
The differences between the rules governing
adversarial discovery in the United States and Europe are significant. In 1938,
the enactment of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure in the United States gave
origin to one of the most far-reaching discovery systems in the world, authorizing
discovery into any matter that is not privileged which is relevant to the subject
matter of the case.
51
As Allen et al pointed out, in most litigation settings modern US
discovery rules make a fetish out of free access to all information, rendering most
of the available evidence discoverable.
52
As Subrin put it, the federal discovery rules
have opened the doors to fishing expeditions through adversarial discovery, where
litigants are allowed access to documents and data of the opposing party for
exploratory reasons in the search for information that may strengthen their case
or weaken the case of their opponent.
53
Rules of civil procedure at the state level
have followed the federal example, introducing some limits on discovery only in
the interest of procedural economy.
The reach of adversarial discovery as practiced in the United States. is not
available in civil law jurisdictions. The non-adversarial procedural traditions of
49
It should be noted that better verifiability of facts reduces the variability in the outcome
of the results: court decisions will be correct more often. The increase in accuracy does not
necessarily affect the parties’ activity levels. The risk of being incorrectly found negligent, and
required to pay damages despite having taken care, does not will deter activities. The increased
variance in judicial outcomes also entails a counterbalancing hope of being incorrectly found
diligent, and required to pay no damages, despite not having taken due care. Unless we assume
that lack of accuracy in adjudication entails a systematic bias toward the incorrect finding of
negligence (with no offsetting dismissals in favor of negligent defendants), on average, courts
unbiased inaccuracy would not affect expected liability and the resulting activity levels.
50
For a formal economic model, assessing the effects of discovery rules on the incentives
to invest in private evidence, see A. Guerra and F. Parisi, n above 47.
51
See US Federal Rules of Civil Procedure, Rule 26.
52
R.J. Allen et al, A Positive Theory of the Attorney-Client Privilege and the Work Product
Doctrine’ 19 Journal Legal Studies, 359 (1990). US evidence law generally makes most of the
available evidence discoverable. See A.R. Miller and C.E. Tucker, Electronic Discovery and the
Adoption of Information Technology 30 The Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization,
217 (2014); R.S. Haydock and D.F. Herr, Discovery Practice (New York: Wolters Kluwer, 2016).
53
S.N. Subrin, Fishing Expeditions Allowed: The Historical Background of the 1938 Federal
Discovery Rules 39 Boston College Law Review, 691 (1998). For example, in United States v
Microsoft, 87 F. Supp. 2d 30 (D.D.C. 2000), prosecutors used e-mails sent between Microsoft
executives to prove anti-competitive intent towards Netscape. For other examples of e-discovery, see
A.R. Miller and C.E. Tucker, n 52 above.
2023] Burdens of Proof in Establishing Negligence 96
Europe adopt a different approach in legal discovery, letting each party produce
the evidence that is available to them, with very narrow use of court-ordered
discovery of evidence.
54
These approaches are deeply entrenched in the civil law
tradition and echoed in current case law, as best exemplified by the rules and
cases governing adversarial discovery in Europe. A few representative examples
are offered below.
The relevant laws governing the discovery of evidence in France are Arts 10,
138, and 139 of the Code of Civil Procedure (Code de procédure civile). Under the
French Code of Civil Procedure Art 10, parties may petition the court to order the
other party or third parties to produce evidentiary material, but the judge’s
decision to allow discovery is discretionary.
55
However, French judges do not allow
adversarial access to evidence for exploratory reasons, and only force production of
evidence in cases where the opposing party already has knowledge of the content of
the sought-after evidence and has no other means to prove its claim (eg, to obtain a
signed agreement that remained in possession of the opposing party).
56
The opportunity for adversarial use of evidence under the Italian Code of
Civil Procedure (Codice di Procedura Civile) is even narrower. Art 670 allows
parties to seek sequestration of physical documentary evidence (now interpreted to
also include electronic, audio, and video evidence) that contains information
already known to the other party and that if later admitted by the court could
be critical for the resolution of the dispute.
57
The role of the sequestration,
reflected in Art 671, is purely conservative: evidence is placed in the trust of a
third party, and it is not given to the opposing party for the search of other
information that could help to corroborate their case. The admissibility of the
preserved evidence in court is governed by Art 210 of the Italian civil procedure
code. Italian case lawranging from trial courts to a recent decision of the Italian
Supreme Court (‘Corte di Cassazione’)—has narrowly interpreted Art 210,
affirming that adversarial discovery is granted at the discretion of the judge, and
should not be granted as an instrument to aid a party in meeting its burden of
proof.
58
Case law restated that the content of the requested evidence should be
known and specified by the requesting party, and discovery should not be asked
54
European legal systems follow a more conservative approach with respect to adversarial
discovery of private evidence. See M.H. Redish, ‘Electronic Discovery and the Litigation Matrix’
51 Duke Law Journal, 561 (2001); G. Foggo et al, Comparing E-Discovery in the United States,
Canada, the United Kingdom, and Mexico, (London: McMillan, 2020). For extensive references, see
T.P. Harkness et al, ‘Discovery in International Civil Litigation: A Guide for judges’ Procedure,
Advocacy, Strategy and Tactics in Arbitration, 14 (2017).
55
G. Serge, F. Frederique and C. Cecile, Procèdure civile (Paris: Dalloz, 2009), 341-42, 341-52.
56
See J. El-Ahdab and A. Bouchenaki, Discovery in International Arbitration: A Foreign
Creature for Civil Lawyers? (Arbitration Advocacy in Changing Times ICCA Congress Series no
15, 2011), 65-117. Requirements on the petitioning party further limit the application and viability of
forced production petitions within the French legal system. P. Harkness et al, n 54 above.
57
For discovery practices in selected jurisdictions, see P. Harkness et al, above n 54.
58
Tribunale di Frosinone 18 April 2018 no 379; Tribunale di Grosseto 7 January 2020 no 8.
97 The Italian Law Journal [Vol. 09 No. 01
for exploratory reasons.
59
If the requesting party fails to specify the exact content of
the document requested through adversarial discovery, the request should be
denied.
60
In 2016, the Italian Supreme Court reaffirmed this principle, highlighting
its rationale when it stated that
the purpose of discovery is not to help the party prove something that
he would not have been able to prove in the absence of the new information
acquired through discovery.
61
The relevant rules governing the adversarial discovery of evidence in Germany
are found in the German Code of Civil Procedure (‘Zivilprozessordnung). Like
its French and Italian counterparts, the German Code of Civil Procedure does not
offer procedures for pretrial discovery similar to those found in US jurisdictions, and
the German principle against the use of discovery for exploratory reasons is
upheld in case law.
62
Furthermore, under German law there is no general obligation
to produce documents to assist the opposing party in transnational litigation.
This procedural principle led Germany to introduce reservations in the ratification
of the Hague Service of Process Convention, which entered into force on 26 June
1979. In ratifying the Hague Convention, Germany introduced declarations and
reservations that excluded the application of Chapter II of the Convention. As a
result, in transnational disputes, Germany will not execute requests of pretrial
discovery of documents as known in the United States (according to Art 23 of the
Declaration).
The differences in the adversarial discovery of private evidence have obvious
consequences on the parties’ incentives to invest in evidence technology. Under
a fully discoverable evidence regime, keeping track of ones actions makes the saved
information subject to being discovered and subpoenaed, and possibly used as
evidence by opposing parties in the event of a dispute. Under US evidence law,
private investments in evidence could thus have a backlash effect on the party
that invested in the technology.
63
As an example, think of a dashboard webcam
that can be installed in a car. If the information gathered by the dashcam could be
59
Tribunale di Spoleto 1 July 2019 no 461.
60
Corte d’Appello di Torino, 8 July 2019 no 1153.
61
Corte di Cassazione 15 March 2016 no 5091.
62
Federal Court of Appeals (BGH) 4 June 1992, NJW 1992, 3096, 3099.
63
F. Parisi et al, Access to Evidence in Private International Law23 Theoretical Inquiries
in Law, 77 (2022), use a simple analytical model to illustrate the effect of these procedural differences
on individualsincentives to invest in private evidence technology, suggesting that the tension
between the retrospective and the prospective effects of discovery of private evidence should be
considered in the allocation of probatory burdens and the design of evidence rules. The impact of
discovery practice on private information technology in the US has been widely documented in
the empirical legal literature. A.R. Miller and C.E. Tucker, n 52 above studied the effects of state
e-discovery rules on the adoption of electronic medical records by hospitals. The study suggests
that in states that adopt e-discovery rules, hospitals reduced the use of electronic records to limit
risks that they could be adversely discovered and used against them in future litigation.
2023] Burdens of Proof in Establishing Negligence 98
used in court against the driver to prove his negligence when his non-negligence
is presumed, the driver may be disincentivized from installing the dashcam.
64
Imagine the case of two individuals facing the risk of an accident in a regime of
negligence liability with a defense of comparative or contributory negligence. The
parties need to decide whether to invest in evidence technology, which can gather
and save information that can be used as evidence in the event of an accident. The
two individuals make their investment decision without knowing whether they
will find themselves in the role of victims or injurers. In the absence of evidence
technology, facts related to the accident are only partially verifiable by the factfinder.
Evidence technology can increase the verifiability of the information presented
by the parties by recording the events of the accident. By investing in evidence
technology, the party facing the burden of producing evidence has an increased
probability to satisfy his or her burden of proof.
However, if the evidence in possession of one party is discoverable by the
opposing party the evidence collected by the technology could be discovered by the
opposing party and would also increase the opposing party’s ability to satisfy its
burden in the event of an accident. In cases characterized by role-uncertainty, such
as ordinary traffic accidents by average drivers, the advantages and disadvantages
of the evidence technology would be offset in most tort situations, eliminating the
parties incentives to invest in new evidence technology. Individuals would invest
in private evidence when undertaking activities that put them in a position of
prospective victims more often than in a position of prospective injurers, and/or
in situations where defenses of contributory or comparative negligence have a high
likelihood of application.
65
Making private evidence discoverable discourages
investments in technology in tort scenarios characterized by symmetric role-
uncertainty.
66
64
In turn, insurance companies would not want to encourage the adoption of dashcams by
offering premium discounts, knowing that the evidence collected by this technology would
increase the exposure of their insureds, with an increase in the expected liability of the insurance
company. Not surprisingly, although in the US several insurance companies offer discounts if
telematic devices without video recording are installed to monitor drivers driving patterns (eg,
Progressive Insurance’s Snapshot
®
), no US insurance company offers premium discounts to
their insureds for installing dashcams with video recording. Conversely, many insurance companies
in Europeand every insurance company in Italyoffer premium discounts to drivers who
voluntarily install webcams on their vehicles. See A. Guerra and F. Parisi, n 47 above.
65
Asymmetries in the partiesrole-probabilities can arise for a variety of reasons: activities
differ in nature; riskier activities are statistically more likely to cause harm to others; parties may
differ in their abilities to undertake effective precautions; etc. When role probabilities are asymmetric
(eg, individuals who fear becoming victims of a tort of trespass or assault) the adoption of
evidence technology, such as a webcams or bodycams, could be beneficial to record information
that could enable victims to produce the necessary evidence against their injurers, with limited
risk of backlash from the adversarial discovery of the evidence.
66
As a plausible development in the future regulatory landscape of jurisdictions with
discoverable evidence, it is conceivable that policies may be introduced to mandate the adoption and
use of recording devices: if such recording devices exist and are not expensive, why should
lawmakers encourage those who are more likely to be in violations of duties of care to shield their
99 The Italian Law Journal [Vol. 09 No. 01
Things work differently when parties operate in jurisdictions that grant limited
discovery of private evidence technology. In the face of a tort scenario with role-
uncertainty, evidence technology will increase a partys ability to satisfy his burden
of production with no backlash effect. When private evidence technology is not
discoverable, the optimal strategy for the parties in both prospective roles as injurers
and victims is to adopt evidence technology when the benefit of the evidentiary
advantage is higher than the cost of acquiring and using the technology. The
adoption of affordable technology becomes a rational decision for both parties.
67
IV. Conclusions
Activities that provide grounds for liability vary in complexity and access to
information. Consider the case in which the injurer’s negligence took the form of
a given action or omission, like speeding above the posted limit. The proof by the
plaintiff that speeding occurred is the equivalent of the proof by the defendant that
speeding did not occur. There is nothing that logic can say about which of the two
parties can more easily prove that fact and should bear the burden of proof in this
case. If one party has better access to that information and can reliably supply new
evidence to the factfinder, the optimal allocation of the burden of proof should then
be on that party. So, if the plaintiff can more easily prove the speed at which the
defendant was driving, thanks to the adoption of third-party evidence technology
(eg, bodycams or other technology that might be available for those types of
accidents), the burden should optimally be imposed on him. Conversely, if the
injurer has a comparative advantage in proving lack of speeding, thanks to first-
party evidence technology available on his car (eg, GPS or Blackbox technology
capable of keeping track of his speed), the burden should optimally fall on him.
68
In many situations, drivers may be better able to keep a complete record of their
own driving speed than prospective victims. Hence, the use of legal presumptions
of negligence for traffic accidents and the resulting adoption of evidence technology
observed in European jurisdictions may well be justified under the cheapest-
evidence-producer criterion.
In this paper, we presented the diverse origin of rules of presumed negligence
and presumed joint negligence in modern and contemporary European systems
and compared their workings to the US system with special attention to negligent
torts. Our discussion emphasized the fact that technology increasingly makes it
possible for parties to keep records of their behavior. For example, car drivers can
have a dashcam or a black box installed on their vehicles, capable of recording speed,
behavior, avoiding the adoption of socially desirable evidence technology?
67
For a formal proof of these results, see the analysis carried out in A. Guerra and F. Parisi,
n 47 above.
68
On this point, see the reliability conditions identified by C.W. Sanchirico, ‘Evidence
Tamperin53 Duke Law Journal, 1215 (2004).
2023] Burdens of Proof in Establishing Negligence 100
braking, and other information. A driver facing a presumption of negligence and a
burden of proving his diligent conduct might have an incentive to invest in a
camera and black box (at least if the driver planned to exercise due care. Investing
in such technology, however, could be to the drivers disadvantage if he failed to
take due care: if a driver exceeded the speed limits or violated other traffic laws
and his devices recorded his behavior, under US discovery rules, his counterpart
in litigation could use the drivers recorded information against him. The more
protective discovery rules followed in European jurisdictions would avoid this
problem and encourage also drivers who are less likely to exercise due care to invest
in evidence technology. The discussion further showed that the use of alternative
legal presumptions leads to the adoption of different types of evidence technology
by different groups of individuals. Presumptions of non-negligence incentivize
prospective victims to adopt third-party focused technology. Presumptions of
negligence incentivize prospective injurers to adopt first-party focused technology.
Presumptions of joint negligence incentivize both prospective victims and
prospective injurers to invest in first party focused technology.
In sum, jurisdictions such as Italy, that limit discovery of private evidence
and adopt presumptions of joint negligence, provide superior tort incentives. By
requiring both parties to provide evidence of their diligent behavior, these
presumptions increase the access to evidence by courts, increasing the accuracy
of adjudication and preserving tort incentives in the face of adjudication errors.
Unfortunately, these conclusions do not provide an easy pathway for legal reform
in different jurisdictions. Procedural rules on adversarial discovery affect the
conditions for the effectiveness of presumptions of negligence and, in a way,
explain the observed differences between the laws of different countries.